Legal Services India - Law Articles is a Treasure House of Legal Knowledge and information, the law resources is an ever growing database of authentic legal information.

» Home
Sunday, April 28, 2024

An Analysis of Cartelization under Indian Competition Law

Posted in: Company law
Sun, Jul 11, 21, 10:58, 3 Years ago
star star star star star
5 out of 5 with 2 ratings
comments: 0 - hits: 11448
The article is a comprehensive study of cartels as understood in the Indian Competition Law Regime

Introduction

In the most basic sense, cartels are such agreements or syndicates operating in a market, which manipulate the prices and production of certain goods, in order to satisfy their own ulterior motives. Cartels are not only extremely detrimental to fair competition, but they also impair the rights of the consumers. In fact, the renowned economist Adam Smith, termed them as ‘conspiracies against public’ in his famous work, The Wealth of Nations[1]. Anti-trust provisions all over the world identify cartels as a major hindrance to a free and fair market, and accordingly different jurisdictions have their own laws to deal with this market menace. This article attempts to analyze the position of cartels under the competition laws of India, through relevant statutory provisions and case laws. It tries to understand the scope of Indian anti-trust provisions on this issue.

 

Cartels and the Indian Competition Act

The Competition Act, 2002[2] (hereinafter referred to as the ‘Act’), is the primary statute in the country that acts as the protector of free and fair competition. Healthy competition is always considered beneficial for the economy, and the Act prohibits any behavior that unfairly benefits someone or causes unfair losses to the other. It also keeps an eye on the abuse of dominant position in the market, and such mergers or acquisitions that have the effect of jeopardizing the consumer’s interests. As defined under section 2(c) of the Act, cartels are an association of producers, sellers, distributors, traders or service providers who, by agreement amongst themselves, limit, control or attempt to control the production, distribution, sale or price of, or, trade in goods or provision of services[3].

To put this simply, cartels are formed when competing enterprises in a market, instead of indulging in fair and healthy competition, come together to fix the prices or production of goods. However, cartels are not only limited to this, and they sometimes also involve allocation of specific markets or consumer bases among the members. Needless to say, these associations are considered to be illegal by the Competition Commission of India (hereinafter referred to as the ‘CCI’). Section 3 of the Act prohibits any such agreements that are anti-competitive in nature and violate the interests of comparatively vulnerable stakeholders such as consumers, and other small businesses.

 

How to prove cartelization?

An important keyword that must be kept in mind while discussing cartels is “agreements”. The Act has incorporated a very wide meaning of the term “agreements”. Under section 2(b) of the Act, agreements are not required to be in writing, or formal, or even legal. Even a meeting of minds and a common understanding is sufficient to prove an agreement. According to the CCI’s reasoning in the case of All India Tyre Dealers’ Federation v. Tyre Manufacturers[4], no explicit agreement is required in order to prove cartelisation, it may be proved even through the intention or conduct of parties. The Act has rightfully drafted such wide clauses. It needs to be understood that cartels are primarily illegal associations of enterprises. The members of a cartel adopt dishonest and unfair measures in order to gain as much profits as possible. They make it difficult for the new entrants in the market to gain reasonable profits and enjoy healthy competition. Obviously, nobody would want such illegal activity to come to light. Hence, it is quite difficult to find concrete evidence for proving cartelisation.

Cartelisation is essentially a civil offence, and hence, the standard of proof in such cases is different. It is not reasonable to expect that proper, well-documented and watertight evidence can be produced in such cases, given the secretive and shadowy nature of the offence. The CCI has evolved an approach that requires only some sort of circumstantial, coherent evidence to prove cartelisation[5]. Initially, the standard of proof in order to substantially prove cartelisation was ascertained in the case of In re sugar mills[6]. In fact, the standards of proof laid down in this case were very difficult to prove for a secretive activity like cartelisation. To prove cartelisation, the requirements were: conclusive evidence of the members meeting and agreeing to take concerted action, the implementation of this concerted action, and a meeting of minds. It goes without saying that proving all these requirements substantially was not an easy task, and hence a risk of cartels not being detected due to want of evidence was always present. The CCI evolved its approach over time and relaxed the criteria in order to prove cartelisation. In the case of Builders Association of India v. Cement Manufacturers' Association & Ors[7], the CCI provided a more lenient standard of proof in cases of cartelisation. In this case, it was held that if it is not possible to prove cartelisation through concrete evidence, even circumstantial evidence can be considered as sufficient proof of cartelisation. Contributing factors such as price parallelism may also be considered in specific cases to determine cartelisation. Further, it is not necessary to prove cartelisation beyond reasonable doubt, even balance of probabilities can be employed as a test to determine cartelisation, as held in the in Re: suo‐motu case against LPG cylinder manufacturer’s case[8]. This simply means that the court can examine different versions of the same case and check which version is more probable to be true.

 

Powers of CCI to impose penalties

The Act includes certain sections that empower the CCI to impose penalties in cases where it is found that there has been an unfair collusion that is having an appreciable adverse effect on competition. If, after a proper investigation, it is found that there has been an illegal collusion by enterprises in order to unfairly increase their profits, the CCI can impose penalties on them. According to Section 27 of the Act, the CCI has the power to impose upon every cartel participant a penalty of up to three times its profit for each year of continuance of the cartel, or up to 10 percent of the turnover for every year of the continuance of the cartel, whichever is higher[9]. However, the CCI may not always impose penalties on cartel members. It can issue other directions as well. Under Section 48 of the Act, the Commission may order the cartel members to discontinue the cartel and not to engage in such activities again[10]. It may also direct the modification of agreements as it deems suitable, and might even impose criminal or additional monetary penalties if the concerned parties act in contravention to the commission’s orders.

 

 

Leniency applications: an important feature

Leniency applications are an important aspect of competition law. It is well known by now that conclusively proving cartelization is a difficult task, and leniency applications provide another way out of this problem. According to the CCI Lesser Penalty Regulations 2009, leniency applications are considered when a member of a cartel agrees to provide material evidence and information about the cartel, and hence cooperates with the CCI to make a strong case against the cartel. It is also necessary that the member seeking leniency does not further participate in the cartel activities. Based on the cooperation and the value of evidence provided, the applicant seeking leniency can be granted from 30-50 to even 100% penalty reduction[11].

 

Conclusion

The Indian Competition Law has been able to incorporate such provisions that can effectively deal with cartels. However, there is a scope of defining proper quantitative penalties in cases of cartelization. The standard of proof can further be defined and made more uniform by including definite criteria in the Act itself. Cartelization is highly detrimental to competition, and efforts must always be made to curb it as effectively as possible.

 

 

[1] Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. Oxford, England: Bibliomania.com Ltd, 2002.

[2] The Competition Act, 2002, Act No. 12 of 2003

[3] Section 2(c), The Competition Act, 2002.

[4] MANU/CO/0097/2012.

[5]  Cyril Shroff and Nisha Kaur Uberoi, Cartel Enforcement in India: Standard and Burden of Proof, CPI Antitrust Chronicle 1 (2013).

[6] MANU/CO/0035/2017.

[7] MANU/CO/0062/2012.

[8] Suo Moto Case No. 03 of 2011

[9] Section 27, The Competition Act, 2002.

[10] Section 48, The Competition Act, 2002.

[11] Cyril Shroff and Nisha Kaur Uberoi, Cartel Enforcement in India: Standard and Burden of Proof, CPI Antitrust Chronicle 1 (2013).

 

Comments

There are no comments for this article.
Only authorized users can leave comments. Please sign in first, or register a free account.
Share
Sponsor
About Author
avikalp1702mishra
Member since Jul 11, 2021
Location: n/a
Following
User not following anyone yet.
You might also like
An article on the objective and importance of RERA in India and also the present scenario of the Act.
The I&B Code does not envisage the adoption of any law, including the UNCITRAL Model law, but only reciprocal arrangements with countries. This is perhaps the biggest flaw in the current insolvency regime in India.
Recent trend of raising false dispute under Insolvency & Bankruptcy Law
The following Article is written by Varun Singh, second year student at RGNUL. It analyses various aspects of cross- border mergers and acquisitions.
This Article gives information of Sec.66 of Companies Act,2013 which deals with Share Capital Reduction.
Deputy Collector & Competent Authority (NSEL) V/s Anil Kohil the National Company Law Tribunal has no jurisdiction to examine the legality or validity of action taken under Maharashtra Protection of Interest of Depositors (In Financial Establishments) Act, 1999 (MPID Act)
Distressed M&As are not new to the Indian economy. In a distressed M&A, both investors and sellers have a lot of research, procedure, and due diligence to undertake in a much shorter amount of time. Handling a distressed M&A is nothing short of an art; it needs exceptional abilities as well as an equally exceptional drive.
The creation of whole in taxation system by legal validation and operations of shelf companies.
An Introduction to corporate law and its implementation
Saurabh vs M.P. that Registrar of Public Trust has no discretionary power under the Madhya Pradesh Public Trust Act, 1951, to remove the existing Trustees and direct the Trust to conduct elections for the same.
A corporate or business entity is basically a composition of its stakeholders- shareholders, directors, employees, and customers, who are involved in the process directly or indirectly
The whole sole purpose of a farmer-producer company is to benefit farmers. A group of farmers or individual producers can leverage the benefits of setting it up and enjoy the schemes run by the government, such as MNREGA, loans, PDS, etc.
Starting a microfinance company in India requires significant planning, funding, and expertise. However, it can be a rewarding business venture that addresses a critical need in the Indian financial services industry.
In this paper, we shall conduct a detailed analysis of CSR in the business realm by delving into its inception, development and present-day implementation.
It analyzes the concept of corporate greenwashing in banking & financial sector. And the case study of GIFT City project alongwith the plausible outcomes it would bring in this project keeping in mind Corporate Greenwashing.
Top